June 15, 2015

Who needs a license to standard essential patents?

Having recently discussed some specific court cases and hot topics, I thought it might be time for a more generic post on licensing concepts and principles. Specifically, I'd like to talk about what I call the "licensing point" for patents in general and Standard Essential Patents (SEP) in particular. Simply put, I'll try to answer the question; "Who needs an SEP license"?

By "licensing point" I mean "the entity among several entities in a product value-chain that obtains a patent license for making or selling products". We know that in the case of mobile phones, the Original Equipment Manufacturer (OEM) - the entity that puts a ready-to-use end-product on the market with a brand name belonging or licensed to it - is the SEP licensing point. In this post I'll discuss why this so, and also whether it's likely to stay that way going forward. 

Generally speaking, the licensing point is ultimately selectable by the patent holder, and could be virtually any entity in the value chain whose product encompasses the inventions covered by the licensed patents. It could be the end-product OEM, a component manufacturer or an entity in-between those. It could even be a point downstream from the OEM, like a whole-seller or a high-street- or Internet retailer. The royalty parameters just need to be properly adjusted in every case to reflect the ultimate license value to the end-product. For sure there can be practical complications in implementing some of these licensing points, but they should be perfectly permissible per se.

But that's more of a theoretical observation, now let's look at specifics. As stated, the OEM happens to be the cellular SEP licensing point. But why is that exactly? As it turns out, there are several reasons

We can start with a simple historical reason. Up until the end of the 1990's, the only OEMs that existed on the mobile device market were all vertical OEMs. So in fact there was only one possible licensing point.

So that was easy. But as we know today, this market structure changed a lot since then, so an interesting question is why the licensing point did not change with it. 

Indeed, the mobile device industry went through a structural change during the first decade of this century. From consisting of only a handful of vertical OEMs, it became more diverse, including a value-chain of specialized entities. This change was initially led by Qualcomm on the chipset level and further downstream by Taiwanese "notebook ODMs". 
  
However, in spite of increased specialization, some vertical or near-vertical OEMs still remained and new ones even emerged. Today there are pure mobile device vertical OEMs (Samsung, LG), pure infrastructure vertical OEMs (Alcatel-Lucent, Ericsson, Nokia) and combined mobile device and infrastructure vertical OEMs (Huawei), all doing pretty well in the marketplace. These companies have substantial in-house knowledge and control of the chain from components or chip-sets all the way down to the manufactured finalized product. So to maintain that position there's a need for these OEMs to invest rather heavily in R&D and standardization, which in turn will also generate SEP portfolios.

Now, for all such SEP-holding OEMs, an interesting question arises; would it be appropriate for the mobile device SEP licensing point to move upstream from the OEM level to e.g. the chipset manufacturer level?

While such a move might seem plausible at first glance, it could lead to complications. To understand this, let's first look at a hypothetical example scenario, but using real-world entities for ease of explanation. Take a SEP-holding mobile device OEM like Samsung. Assume that Samsung would license its SEP portfolio at a point upstream from the OEM level, let's say to chipset maker Mediatek.
Now as long as another SEP-holding OEM, for example Huawei, located downstream from Mediatek would not assert its SEP portfolio against Samsung, this would be just fine. But if it would - and it likely would because Huawei would have a FRAND commitment as an SEP holder - then Samsung might have reasons for concern. In the example scenario, while Samsung needs an SEP license from Huawei, things are not as obvious regarding Huawei's need of an SEP license from Samsung. In many jurisdictions, Samsung's license to Mediatek can be seen as inherently providing certain rights to Huawei under Samsung's patents, for products that include Mediatek's chipsets. So in effect, Samsung's license to Mediatek could limit its own defenses against an SEP portfolio assertion by Huawei against Samsung's products.

However, if Samsung would instead continue to consistently license the last point in the chain -  in this example Huawei - then no such issue would occur. Then Samsung could procure a maximally efficient SEP portfolio cross-license with Huawei because it's 100% clear that Huawei needs a full license from Samsung, regardless of what chipsets happen to reside in its products. This so-called "grant-back" issue is one reason why the cellular SEP licensing point prevails at the OEM level also in today's more specialized world.

Now those particular companies were used only as examples, and I don't know the real licensing situations among them. But the example illustrates that at least as long as there remain SEP-holding mobile and/or infrastructure OEMs - which tend to be verticals - generally healthy and successful in the global marketplace, this will be a continuing factor that tends to keep the SEP licensing point for mobile devices at the OEM level.

But there are also other reasons for the OEM being the licensing point. Like the issue of "patent value apportionment". A license to an SEP portfolio needs to be priced based on the value the technical inventions therein bring to the end-product. In US law this has been made clear in e.g. the well-known CSIRO vs. Cisco and Ericsson vs. D-Link et. al. cases. And the easiest point to observe the value the inventions bring to the end-product is - not surprisingly - at the end-product level, i.e. the OEM level.

We can look at the illustrating example of the iPod Touch vs. the iPhone. These products are very much alike, with the difference largely being that one has cellular connectivity and the other one doesn't. The products have similar specs and both carry the "brand magic" of the OEM, Apple. Yet today's price difference between the two is around $250

As I mentioned in another post, the price difference not only illustrates the tremendous value of adding standardized cellular technology to an otherwise similar device. It also indicates the value of a license to the SEP portfolios covering it. Due to the way standards are created, the SEP portfolios covering a standard include those innovative technologies that won the competitive race to allow that particular standard to fulfil its specific requirements. Therefore the accumulation of SEP portfolios for a standard do in fact drive the value of the standard itself.

The market has established the accumulated SEP portfolio license value for a mobile device to be somewhere close to 10% of the OEM selling price of the end-product. This is a fraction of the value the standard itself brings to the end-product, but also more than the cost of a chipset. Clearly, when component suppliers don't account for SEP license costs, the component prices don't reflect the value of SEP portfolio licenses to the end-product at allAnother way of viewing this is that if the licensing point would hypothetically move to the chipset level, the chipset cost would have to increase many-fold. That may seem odd at first, but remember that this is accounting for the value to the end-product.

There are some recent and quite loud voices in the industry that - notably without rational or legal support - advocate that basing wireless SEP license royalties on end-product price is "non-FRAND", and that such royalties "must" be based on the chipset value. Actually, such calls are not always explicitly about moving the licensing point to the chipset level per se. Indeed, licensing point and royalty base are separate things. With the licensing point kept at the OEM level, a chipset value royalty base could still be possible in principle, by setting the royalty rate to some hundreds of percent. Ultimately, the royalty base is just a parameter in a certain calculation model, and what matters in the end is the value to the end-product. 

Another related factor driving the OEM licensing point is that the value of the standard may be different for different end-products. Since the value of licenses to the accumulation of SEP portfolios is proportional - but not equal - to the value of the standard, the license value can also vary between different end-products. For a mobile phone the value is very obviously large, but there are end-products for which the value might be considered smaller. For a vending machine or utility meter for example, the standardized cellular connectivity - and a license to all patented inventions therein - might for various reasons not necessarily be considered as tremendously valuable as for a mobile phone. Now if the licensing point would be moved to the chipset level, there'd be an issue with chipset tracability, or rather the lack of it. In fact, chipset manufacturers don't always know what type of end-product their chipsets ultimately end up in. Consequently it can be hard to determine the appropriate end-product license value at the chipset level. 

In this post, I've outlined some rational reasons for why SEP-holding OEMs conclude SEP portfolio licenses at the end-product OEM level. While it's certainly possible that this might change in the future, my guess is that some factors that make it rational to keep the licensing point at the OEM level will prevail for some time to come.

June 09, 2015

More evidence of reverse patent hold-up in SEP FRAND licensing


Today we can dismiss the notion of "patent hold-up" occurring in wireless SEP FRAND licensing. In spite of extensive searches with powerful magnifying glasses, courts and agencies have found no evidence of it, and neither have academics.

On the other hand, when it comes to the opposite behaviour, "reverse patent hold-up" (also called "patent hold-out"), it's unfortunately widespread.

We received yet another example of this in a recent US International Trade Commission (ITC) ruling in IDC vs Nokia/Microsoft. To begin with, the ITC not only concludes that "There is no evidence of patent hold-up" but also provides a beautifully natural explanation for the general absence of actual patent hold-up in the SEP and FRAND context: "In the current state of IP law as it relates to SSOs and IPRs, an owner of a SEP has a long list of government agencies, law professors, and companies watching what the company does and attempting to change the law as to potential outcomes. [Microsoft] stated they are afraid that if IDC obtained an exclusion order, then they would use it to gain undue leverage and obtain compensation above the FRAND rate. This is unlikely because too many hostile eyes are watching. The fact that ITC has been watching since at least 2011, and not found such a violation, makes it unlikely it would happen here for the first time.

In other words, because patent hold-up is such an obvious and grave concern, there are too many critical and powerful and onlookers to allow it to actually happen.  

On the other hand, for reverse patent hold-up there are clearly too few onlookers. In case after case we see infringers shown to act in bad faith, while comments and discussions on this phenomenon are hardly noticeable. In the above-mentioned case, the ITC concluded that there was again "evidence of reverse patent hold-up" and pointed out that "There is however, one course of action that can clearly demonstrate bad faith, and that is a failure to meaningfully negotiate. ... Other evidence that supports the finding of reverse holdup is the clear gain that occurs daily for [Microsoft]...Each day that the respondents use the patents without taking a license, IDC loses money that it will not be able to recover."

Thankfully, at least some onlookers that really matter in the end - courts and agencies - remain vigilant about reverse patent hold-up.

There are previous examples of similar behaviour and findings as I've discussed in previous posts. For example, such findings may be found in Apple vs. Samsung in the Korean Fair Trade Commission and the US ITC and in Ericsson vs. D-Link in the US Federal Circuit.
 
It's also important to realize that the phenomenon is not limited to those few companies. Reverse patent hold-up is a globally widespread behaviour, with negative consequences for innovation incentivization and licensing efficiency. It's also a major driver behind SEP divestments and so-called "patent privateering" that FOSS Patents' Florian Mueller has started a campaign against
So clearly, courts and agencies outside the US need to be as alert and forceful as their US counterparts in properly combating it.